Image: Water Lily #2

March 23, 2018


Night Music: Big Yellow Taxi

March 22, 2018

Story Time On The Drive

March 22, 2018

Thanks to the always useful ILiveInEastVancouver blog, I learn that The Drive Coffee Bar at 1670 Commercial is hosting a weekly story session each Wednesday evening from 7:30pm to 9:00pm:

“You will hear tales from some seasoned storytellers, but each week they do try and get a new face up to take a turn.  The venue is a favourite of ours for the great coffee, selection of Cartem Donuts and some of the best sandwiches in the City by La Grotta del Fromaggio plus they also serve wine and beer.”

Sounds like a fun evening!


Book Review: “Move Fast and Break Things”

March 21, 2018

Global headlines this week about the follies of Facebook provided the perfect backdrop for reading Jonathan Taplin’s “Move Fast and Break Things” in which he describes the damage to culture and society caused by Facebook, Google, and Amazon.

Taplin is well placed to tell this story, having begun his multiple careers working with the Band and Bob Dylan before moving on to become a film producer (“Mean Streets”, “The Last Waltz”, “Until the End of the World”, etc). He joined the University of Southern California faculty in 2004 and is now the Director Emeritus of the Innovation Lab at the Annenberg School for Communication and Journalism. The author is therefore well versed in the cultural aspects of his subject; however, early on, he notes that “[w]hat I mistook as only a culture war is an economic war … Monopoly, control of our data, and corporate lobbying are at the heart of this story.”

The Big Three (Facebook, Google/Alphabet, and Amazon) are rentiers of the classic type, with their monopolies of a scarce and valuable resource. Taplin notes that they have been allowed to become so powerful because “since the rise of the Internet, policy makers have acted as if the rules that apply to the rest of the economy do not apply to Internet monopolies.”  He explains this with an in-depth look at how the technology companies have mastered regulatory capture, which “is the process by which regulatory bodies eventually come to be dominated by the very industries they were charged with regulating.”

Mark Zuckerberg/Peter Thiel

Taplin spends some time discussing the Ayn Rand-style libertarianism of technology leaders such as Peter Theil, Jeff Bezos, Larry Page, and Mark Zuckerburg; and he provides a useful history of corporate dominance stretching from Hamilton’s victory over Madison and Jefferson through Robert Bork’s free market philosophy and on to the victory of the corporations in the Citizens United case. Noting that “the average citizen has voluntarily (though unknowingly) turned over to Google and Facebook far more personal information than the government will ever have,” he declares that the “tightening monopolization of US industry is rendering America an oligarchy” with profound and disturbing consequences for democracy.

Taplin quotes Robert McChesney: “many of the successful [Internet] giants … were begun by idealists who may have been uncertain whether they really wanted to be old-fashioned capitalists. The system in short order has whipped them into shape.”  And just this week, Roger B. McNamee, an early investor in Facebook, was quoted in the New York Times as saying: “I couldn’t believe these guys I once knew so well had gotten so far off track.”

Move Fast” is larded with interesting vignettes from the music, film, and computer industries, many of which are written with first-hand experience. Taplin is an excellent writer, moving fluently from one part of the story to the next, never getting bogged down in the details but ensuring we have the necessary information.

The book finishes with Taplin’s proposals for how this situation could be reversed. He suggests a local control model such as in Chattanooga which controls broadband as a local utility; or turning telecommunications into a “natural utility” regulated by federal government agencies; or using a co-op model for all content creation. However, sadly, he doesn’t really succeed in convincing us that any of these solutions will happen anytime soon.

Move Fast and Break Things” (2017, Little Brown & Co) is available at the People’s Coop Bookstore on Commercial Drive.

Image: Sky Meld

March 21, 2018

Generation Squeeze’s Code Red Policy Statement

March 20, 2018

Generation Squeeze (GS) is an advocacy group that has been around for a couple of years, but which has come to the fore more prominently as the Vancouver municipal election approaches.

Their website describes GS as the younger generation’s version of the Canadian Association of Retired Persons. Their primary focus is on the difficulties younger Canadians have in the housing market, especially in Vancouver. In 2016 they produced a research and policy document called “Code Red: Rethinking Canadian Housing Policy” which I believe still represents their policy today. I have been reading the document and the following are my comments.

The first half of the paper consists of solid research including graphs and tables illustrating the development of the affordability crisis for young Canadians seeking housing. It is a tough read and things have only gotten worse since it was written, with land values and housing costs having continued to soar over the last two years. Of particular concern is a graph showing the change over the last forty years in the time it takes an average young Vancouverite to save a 20% down payment:


For those still unclear on what the problems are for the younger generation, this will be a useful read and perhaps a necessary piece of education.  Missing from this section is any analysis of (a) the consequences of enormous foreign capital inputs to the Vancouver market; and (b) the fact that Vancouver is such a low income city which, of course, has a direct effect on affordability.

The GS paper goes on to discuss ten possible solutions, or at least routes to solutions. They are grouped into tax changes to moderate demand for housing, housing supply, and non-housing costs.

First, they call for capital gains tax to be imposed on property transactions within 24 months at a sliding scale. This is something I have been calling for but I would stretch the time and keep the rate the same.  I would impose capital gains tax on all property transactions, including “shadow flipping,” with a deduction equal to the general inflation rate for the period between sales, plus costs of genuine improvements, for at least five years.

Then they propose a home valuation tax, a wealth tax on property. Seniors would be exempt and this tax would be offset against any income tax paid in Canada so it becomes, in effect, a tax on non-residents. The theory is that any collections on this tax would be paid into a Housing Affordability Fund. GS suggests a progressive tax based on median value in the region and suggests this would encourage developers to build housing at prices lower than the media value. This appears to deal with several problems at once but, frankly, it seems way too complicated and thus open to abuse.

This wealth tax is expanded in their next point where they suggest that property wealth should be considered when deciding how much people (seniors mainly) should pay for services such as health care.  They spend a whole page justifying this, but fail to convince that this anything but blatant ageism. And, if you are going to do this, why limit it to housing wealth?

The ageism is expanded in their following point where they suggest that those under 40 should be exempt from such wealth taxes by the introduction for that age group of mortgage interest deductions. I happen to support mortgage interest deduction from income taxes; it works well in the UK and the US and many other jurisdictions to assist people get into the house purchase market. But basing it solely on age is simply discriminatory. It seems clear that they want to foster age warfare rather than, say, class warfare.

Their final two propositions in the tax category once again attack what they see as advantages given to seniors (primarily the interest charges on property tax deferrals).  They believe that these advantages should be transferred to the younger age group based on what I think is less than conclusive evidence that seniors are better able to pay than they used to be.

The next section of the GS paper deals with Supply. Like other primarily supplyist groups, GS seem to believe that zoning restrictions in SFD neighbourhoods are the main cause of our housing problems. There is no recognition that only 16% of Vancouver’s “single family detached” houses actually house only one family. Nearly all of Grandview, for example, is already zoned as duplex, and a huge percentage have additional suites (legal or otherwise) which provide a good percentage of “affordable” rentals in the area. I have suggested ways in which Grandview’s density could be doubled without much additional building, and at costs far lower than new development.

GS’s complaints that “modest-sized homes with yards are being replaced with very large single detached homes that fill entire properties” is definitely not true in my neighbourhood where “modest sized homes” with affordable suites are being replaced by unaffordable townhouses and the threat of exclusive condo towers that no young Vancouverite could possibly afford.

However, in the following proposition calling for more rental accommodation I agree with GS’s observation that the building of condos in massive numbers under Vision Vancouver has significantly and negatively affected the availability of affordable rental.  They call for “tax incentives” to persuade developers to create purpose built rentals rather than condos.  However, there is no analysis of the failure of Vision Vancouver’s Rental100 incentives to create rentals that are actually affordable.

Finally, they note the recent Federal and Provincial programs to put money into specifically low-income housing. They complain that, even with the billions being talked about, the number of such housing units will barely touch the need. However, I didn’t see any alternative suggestions from them.

One of the important failures in this document is the lack of a definition of genuine “affordability.”  This is a failure that seems to be endemic among supplyist groups, perhaps because developers don’t want to reduce their profits to achieve the affordability targets that would match Vancouver’s income levels. Without such an agreed definition, then, as famously defined by Councillor Kerry Jang,  “affordable is whatever you can afford,” which helps no one, especially the low income younger workers, and leads to giveaways to developers for building studios at $1,500 a month.

I have called Generation Squeeze a supplyist group on a number of occasions in this piece. That characterization is not immediately clear when reading Code Red. But the company they keep is illustrative. They have funding from the developers’ group, UDI, and I believe, directly from developers. Some might say, so what? But it is naive to believe that funding doesn’t influence policy — if that was not the case, there would have been no reason for the Provincial government to amend the Campaign Financing Act to rid our elections of big money.

In conclusion, the policies listed in Code Red, and the age warfare that lies behind them, are a serious disappointment after the research that goes before.


Night Music: Take Five

March 20, 2018